Elsevier

Health Policy

Volume 115, Issues 2–3, April 2014, Pages 230-236
Health Policy

Two-part payments for the reimbursement of investments in health technologies

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.healthpol.2013.10.006Get rights and content

Abstract

The paper studies the impact of alternative reimbursement systems on two provider decisions: whether to adopt a technology whose provision requires a sunk investment cost and how many patients to treat with it. Using a simple economic model we show that the optimal pricing policy involves a two-part payment: a price equal to the marginal cost of the patient whose benefit of treatment equals the cost of provision, and a separate payment for the partial reimbursement of capital costs. Departures from this scheme, which are frequent in DRG tariff systems designed around the world, lead to a trade-off between the objective of making effective technologies available to patients and the need to ensure appropriateness in use.

Introduction

Although there is agreement that the diffusion of new health care technology has led to substantial improvement in patient outcomes [1], the sustainability of its impact on health care expenditure is often questioned [2], [3]. For the US, Smith et al. [4] estimate that medical technology diffusion is responsible for 27–48% of total expenditure growth. It is often argued that at least part of this increase is due to inappropriateness in use [5].

Both adoption decisions and subsequent use of the new technology contribute to determining overall efficiency in this field. In the quest to improve value for money of technological diffusion, regulators have employed a wide range of instruments, both direct – ex-ante assessments by HTA national agencies, Certificates of Need like those employed in several U.S. states – and indirect – price regulation in (quasi-)competitive markets. The impact of these policies on adoption and use of the technologies has been widely investigated within two largely independent strands of literature.1 Adoption is studied regardless of use, whereas appropriateness is studied conditional on an adoption decision. In this paper we argue that if adoption requires a sunk investment cost, the regulatory issues concerning the decisions on whether to adopt the new technology and to whom the treatment should be provided should be studied together. The most obvious example of technology requiring an investment cost is equipment. However, from the technical point of view, our results are equally relevant to any other situation where a fixed cost (e.g. training) must be paid before some kind of treatment is provided to patients.

We study indirect regulation, through prices. A specific fee-for-service tariff may exist for the reimbursement of treatments involving one technology (e.g. diagnostics for outpatient care), or the reimbursement can be part of the DRG price. Our analysis applies to both situations, as long as at least part of the DRG price is meant to reimburse the treatment provided with the technology of interest.

The efficiency of purely prospective prices has been thoroughly investigated. The literature has shown that it is optimal to add a cost sharing component to the contract if the provider has better information about costs than the purchaser [22], [23], [24], [25]. The presence of a sunk investment cost is in principle another specific economic condition of interest, which seems to have been overlooked in the literature so far.

This paper uses a very simple model to highlight some of the fundamental policy implications derived in a fully stochastic and dynamic framework by Levaggi et al. [13], and to compare them with existing approaches to regulation in this area. We show that when the cost to invest in a technology is sunk, the optimal pricing policy involves a two-part payment: a price equal to the marginal cost of the patient whose benefit of treatment equals the cost of provision, and a separate payment for the partial reimbursement of capital costs. Departures from this scheme, which are frequent in health care systems, lead to a trade-off between the objective of providing patients with effective technologies and the need to ensure appropriateness in use. In particular, wider diffusion can only be achieved at the price of reduced appropriateness in use. However, a two-part payment is not per se sufficient to achieve efficiency, because the levels of the two parts should also be efficiently set. Failures to do so may lead to under- or over-provision of equipment with costly duplications, as well as under- or over-provision of treatments. The variability of tariffs that can be observed, sometimes even within the same health care system, suggests that this may be a further area of regulatory failure.

In the following section we describe the regulatory solutions adopted in a number of countries for the reimbursement of treatments provided with technologies that have the characteristics of interest. Section 3 presents the simple model and Section 4 describes the characteristics of an optimal reimbursement policy. Section 5 links the theoretical results of Section 4 to the real world reimbursement policies introduced in Section 2 and discusses the implications of departing from the optimal rule. Section 6 concludes.

Section snippets

Capital cost reimbursement around the world

The recent completion of the Euro-DRG project2 has shed light on implementation of DRG systems across several European countries along a number of dimensions [26].3 Table 1 integrates a similar table reported in the appendix to Scheller-Kreinsen et al. [27] with additional sources [28], [29], [30], to

A simple regulatory model

Let us consider the decision whether to invest in a new technology and the definition of the number of patients to treat with it. μ defines the incremental effectiveness of the new technology; the total monetary benefit to treat x patients is μb(x), with b(·) increasing and concave, i.e. the marginal incremental benefit is decreasing in the number of patients treated.

As Fig. 1 shows, the benefit of each single treatment falls as the number of treatments increases (MB curve). This reflects the

Optimal two-part payment

In this section we characterize the optimal regulatory policy relying on economic and graphic intuition only. The interested reader may find the analytical solution in the appendix.

Payment rules in practice

The previous section has shown that in the presence of sunk capital costs a two-part payment can be designed to provide appropriate incentives toward both adoption and use of a technology. With reference to Table 1, this scheme would imply a ‘No’ in the first column and a ‘Yes’ in the second. The table shows that, among the countries considered, a similar scheme is adopted only in six countries.11

Conclusions

The diffusion of large scale medical equipment may have substantial impacts on health care expenditure. It is then essential to grant rapid access to patients who can benefit from the technology, while avoiding costly duplications and inappropriateness in use. The economic implications of the decision for the provider are different from those related to the adoption of technologies involving no investment costs (e.g. devices). The present paper studies how regulation should account for these

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to the Editor and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. We would also like to thank Kurt Brekke, Luca Crivelli, Alexander Geissler, Sverre Grepperud, Bjarke Hoijard, Tor Iversen, Michael Khun, Bill LeBlanc, Matte Matthiasen, Glen Muscat, Vincenzo Rebba and Is Yong for useful discussion on the characteristics of national reimbursement systems. Mistakes are the responsibility of the authors.

References (36)

  • D.M. Cutler et al.

    Is technological change in medicine worth it?

    Health Affairs

    (2001)
  • K. Dybczak et al.

    The role of technology in health care expenditure in the EU

    European Economy – Economic Papers 400

    (February 2010)
  • A. Chandra et al.

    Technology growth and expenditure growth in health care. NBER Working Papers 16953

    (2011)
  • S. Smith et al.

    Income insurance and technology: why does health spending outpace economic growth?

    Health Affairs

    (2009)
  • OECD

    Value for money in health spending. Health policy studies

    (2010)
  • D. Dranove et al.

    Recent theory and evidence on competition in hospital markets

    Journal of Economics and Management Strategy

    (1994)
  • T. Bresnahan et al.

    Entry and competition in concentrated markets

    Journal of Political Economy

    (1991)
  • G.A. Melnick et al.

    The effects of market structure and bargaining position on hospital prices

    Journal of Health Economics

    (1992 October)
  • Cited by (10)

    • Investment and quality competition in healthcare markets

      2022, Journal of Health Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      They find that efficiency can be ensured both in the time of adoption (dynamic efficiency) and the intensity of use of technology (static efficiency) if reimbursement by the purchaser includes both a variable (per-patient) component and a lump-sum component.5 A similar conclusion is reached by Levaggi et al. (2014), who show that it is optimal to pay the provider based on a fixed fee per patient and a lump-sum component to fund capital costs separately, a result which loosely resembles some of the insights derived in our welfare analysis. Another key issue, with important regulatory implications, is contractibility.

    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text